First, ‘unintended’ consequences are generally the ones that are not predictable. Like the social changes in teenage life from the rise of the automobile. So let’s talk about the conequences that are pretty predictable, have happened elsewhere, but still get neglected in discusssions of implementing socialized medicine:
[ul]
[li]Waiting Lists. This is inevitable. When you lower the cost for something, demand increases unless the demand is completely inelastic. If demand increases and supply remains the same, you have a gap. In a free market system, the gap is closed by increased prices, which lower demand and stimulate supply. In a command economy, you wind up with shortages. [/li]
If you would like the see the waiting lists currently in Alberta, you can go to this link. Bear in mind that Alberta spends more than average on health care in Canada, and wait lists are even worse in many other provinces.
For example, at the University of Alberta hospital at this moment, there are 2,785 patients on the waiting lists for an MRI scan, and the wait time is THIRTY FIVE WEEKS. Need knee replacement surgery? Expect to hobble for a while. The waiting list at the U of A is currently 61 weeks.
[li]Doctor and nurse shortages. This is unpredictable, because in other countries when they institute socialized medicine the doctors and nurses tend to flee to the U.S. If the U.S. does it, I don’t know where they’ll go. But once the government starts paying doctor salaries, there will be pressure to keep them in check. Again, if you reduce the value of something, you’ll get less of it.[/li]
[li]All kinds of distortions due to politics. Once health care enters the realm of politics, it becomes subject to political favoratism, horse trading, etc. Districts with powerful constituencies will get the newest, biggest facilities, even if they don’t need them. Poorer districts or ‘safe’ districts that politicians can ignore will get the shaft. [/li][/ul]
We’re entering new territory here, because the U.S. has been the ‘escape valve’ of other socialized medical systems. Because the rich in Canada get the same care as the poor if they stay in Canada, the very rich go to the U.S. for treatment. This offloads a substantial burden on our system. But if the U.S. socializes health care, where will your rich go? I predict the rise of ‘health care states’. You already see this in some island countries and plastic surgery or treatment that gets around drug and medical device regulation in other countries. Maybe Bermuda will start building advanced hospitals to pay for the wealthy Americans who want better treatment they can’t get at home. This will also give the best doctors a place to flee to when the U.S. government tries to control them.
It remains to be seen what will happen to medical research - much of which is undertaken because of the high profits available from catering to the wealthy. Limit what the wealthy can pay, and it might not be healthy for research.
I don’t know about ‘duty’, but if the U.S. is anything like Canada, you’ll start hearing arguments like this, “Since we taxpayers are paying for your health, we have a right to prevent you from doing X” (‘X’ being overeating, smoking, riding without a helmet, not wearing seatbelts, or anything else the nanny-statists want to stop you from doing). This is a powerful argument against socialized medicine - once the state is paying the bills, it gives the state an ‘in’ to start eroding your civil liberties.
I don’t see much of a connection here. Canada is more likely to legalize drugs than is the U.S., and we have socialized medicine. I don’t think the issues are related.
Eventually, probably. If the move to socialized medicine were revenue-neutral, it would all eventually come out in the wash. But I don’t think this is the case.
The best doctors will get paid less. The worst will get paid more. There will be less of an incentive to excel, and less of an incentive to work harder to get into the best schools so you can get the best jobs.