Okay, 50K sounds like a more reasonable number, but I still don’t understand how it can be applied in any reasonably rigorous way to an event 50 years in the future. Also, you again would have to apply a discount rate.
A quick digression: You expressed confusion about the discount rate, so let me give you a quick example. Let’s say we need to pay off a 1 trillion dollar insurance claim in 2109. We know that bill is coming. How much money would it cost us today to eliminate that liability? Well, if we earned 3% on our money, we could take out a 100 year T-Bill for $47 million dollars (if such a thing existed), and in 100 years, it would be worth a trillion bucks. So 47 million is the net present value of a 100 trillion liability owed 100 years from now. It’s absolutely critical to factor this in to any activities today that have payoffs in the future.
We have absolutely no idea what kind of effects these would be. For all we know, global efforts to mitigate damage could bring people closer together and improve the geopolitical situation. And for that matter, if you want to include that, we’ll have to include the costs today of geopolitical instability introduced by driving up energy prices and attempting to enforce climate treaties. So I’d suggest we just ignore this.
Another completely unquantifiable effect. And you’d have to consider the opportunity cost of diverting resources to those things instead of all the other things we could be doing.
I completely reject this line of thinking. The notion that you can increase economic efficiency and create economic growth through government spending is flawed, in my opinion. Every dollar the government spends is a dollar that is taxed or borrowed from the larger economy.
You can’t even make a ‘stimulus’ argument, since the debt will have to be paid back during the timeframe in question. The only way you can make the claim that government ‘investment’ will create net economic growth is if you believe that governments are better at allocating goods and services than is the market. And every history we have of government planning suggests that the opposite is true.
So again, to avoid this turning into a partisan slinging match, I suggest that this whole line of thinking be dropped.
Going forward, I suggest we focus on the following things:
- Come to an agreement on the discount rate. This is not going to be a trivial exercise, but we can start by figuring out the low end and high end of current estimates. Stern’s .1 % is clearly the low end, On the high end, the OMB used a rate much higher rate of 10% when calculating the present value of future lives saved. It uses this to do cost-benefit analysis of regulatory costs such as drug trials and social costs such as that of cigarette smoking. This was challenged in court and lowered to 7%. Here’s a legal brief that I believe was used to argue for a lower discount rate for human life of around 1%.
Really, there are two different discount rates we should use. One would be the discount rate against future economic damage. That I think is more straightforward - simply use the average funds rate for economic investment. The other is the ‘social discount rate’ of lives lost or quality of life in the future, and this one is much, much harder to figure out because it involves issues of philosophy and non-economic factors. One paper I read argued that you could use the current savings rates, which indicate the real preference of people for quality of life in the future vs quality of life now. I think that’s specious reasoning. I did a little scanning of the some of the literature around this, and as best I can tell most estimates fall in the range of 1% to 3%.
-
If we can agree on that, then let’s look at the IPCCs estimates for future warming and economic damage and work the cost of the median, then work the cost of the high and low models and come up with some kind of average number. Hopefully, we can separate out economic effects from costs in terms of lives, so we can apply our different discount rates to each.
-
Apply the discount rates, and see what we come up with for the net present value of a ton of carbon, which should tell us how drastic the solution needs to be.
Anyway, that’s the way I’d approach the problem. If we can get that far in the debate, then we can move on to discussing how to actually implement some kind of plan to slow down warming. From this point, we’d then have to start all over on the cost side by looking at the costs of various solutions, and how much warming each one could prevent, to determine if it’s worth doing.