But that’s not the whole story of how it works out. I’d be fine even with the incestuous board of directors creating circle jerk compensation packages such as these if it were actually based on medium term stock performance like you outline.
But what really happens is if the stock doesn’t perform, CxOs realize they won’t get their millions and have to try to survive on just their salary, so get their options repriced so they can rake in the millions anyway, so there’s no risk of failure.
(a) Because I’ve been a lawyer for 12 years. Fraud is part and parcel of the way American ‘capitalism’ (as losely defined) works. In this case he got away with it. So the system protected his actions. What would inspire you to believe fraud is not a part of US style capitalism?
(b) I bet his wife thinks he’s a hero. I could name a few more people too. What makes you think no-one thinks he’s a hero?
The one thing not considered in this analysis is the gain from a general market gain and a gain from Cecil’s stewardship. If S&P (or some analogous companies to Cecil’s) went up 15% a year during this period, Cecil is a chump and deserves nothing. If they went up 5% a year (or went down) Cecil has likely added value to his company, and does deserve his reward.
BTW, Dan Ariely notes that CEO salaries were somewhat more rational before they got published. Though the purpose was to shame boards into limiting executive pay, what actually happened is execs told compensation committees that they deserved more than that guy over there.
I commented on that earlier - that the problem with typical options is that the reward keeping up with the market (or less). Premium priced options are a better choice for many firms, or performance share plans with payouts in restricted shares.
I agree that the public information created an arms race (and a lot of billable hours for me back in the 90s). However, the alternative was not knowing what peer firm CEOs were making. I will take more knowledge over less.