Let’s be careful about the money side of it - economic growth is not about having more money. If it were, you could ‘grow’ the economy by just printing boatloads of bills.
I think a lot of economic thinking gets derailed when people equate money with wealth. Money is an abstraction - a way to come up with a mechanism for exchanging goods and services in an efficient way.
The wealth of a country is not measured in how much currency it has floating around - the wealth of a country is measured by the physical infrastructure it has built, the aggregate sum of goods that exist, and its capability to build products and services that people need. Money is just the way we keep track of it all.
Here’s a good example of how trade between two people can result in economic growth:
Let’s say I’m really good at building chairs. I can build 10 chairs a day. Bob, on the other hand, is really good at building tables - he can build 5 tables a day. But I’m lousy at building tables, and he’s lousy at building chairs. If I build tables, I can only build one a day. If he builds chairs, he can only build 5 a day.
So, let’s say we don’t trade, but we each build sets of tables with four chairs. I spend four days building 40 chairs, then 10 days to build the 10 tables to go with them. Fourteen days to build 10 table and chair sets.
At the same time, Bob spends 8 days to build 40 chairs, then two days to build the 10 tables to go with them.
So between us, if we don’t trade, it takes us 24 man-days to build 20 table and chair sets. Note that Bob is better at this than I am, and if he doesn’t trade with me, he’ll eventually have a lot more than I will. So why would he trade? Let’s work it out:
Let’s say that I spend all my time building chairs - the thing I’m best at. Bob spends his time building tables. In 14 days, I can build 140 chairs. In the same 14 days, Bob can build 70 tables. So now, instead of having 20 tables and 80 chairs, we have 70 tables and 140 chairs - by trading we both benefit, even though Bob is more productive than I am.
This is the law of comparative advantage, and it drives trade. It basically means that you are better off focusing your efforts on the thing that you do best relative to everyone else, and then trading some of what you made for the other things you need.
This is why economics is not a zero-sum game, and why free trade is so important to economic growth (free trade in the macro country vs country sense, and free trade in the sense of all the little market transactions being allowed to happen without government interference).
It’s important to note that comparative advantage still works even if Bob is better than I am at making both tables AND chairs. Let’s say Bob can make five tables a day, but he can also make 15 chairs. In his 14 days, he’ll have 35 tables and 75 chairs. But if he focuses on making tables, where his comparative advantage over me is the greatest, then after 14 days he will have made 70 tables. In the meantime, I’ll have made 140 chairs. But a table to me is worth 10 chairs, because I can make 10 chairs in the time it takes me to make a table. So all Bob has to do is trade 8 of his tables for 75 chairs - I make a 5 chair ‘profit’ by trading, and Bob winds up with his 75 chairs plus 62 tables - a huge advantage for him. We still both profit from trade, even though Bob is better at making everything than I am. He’s just WAY better at making tables, so its to his advantage to focus on what he does best.
In the macro sense, economies grow for several reasons. One is rising worker productivity. If workers can learn to make more with less, then the aggregate output of goods and services grows for the same amount worked. This can happen through innovative business processes, automation, or other capital investment. Assembly line workers in auto plants aren’t worth $35/hr because they are in a union - they’re worth $35/hr because each worker has hundreds of thousands to millions of dollars worth of capital investment helping to make his labor more efficient.
Another way the economy can grow is through investment in new infrastructure - a new factory, better roads to make transportation more efficient, etc. Now the same country is making more stuff.
Another way an economy can grow is through making the entire production chain more efficient. For example, ‘just in time’ inventory practices which have reduced the amount of our wealth tied up in static inventories of goods, which has allowed that wealth to be used for more capital investment. The internet has removed a lot of barriers to trade - think of all the random stuff that gets traded on eBay - in each case moving from someone who values it less than the purchaser. This is highly efficient.
Another way an economy can grow is by removing roadblocks to trade, both internal and external. Trade tariffs distort the market and cause inefficiencies. Let’s go back to our table and chair makers. Let’s say that a politician introduces the ‘chairmakers protection act’, designed to protect me from rich Bob (he’s rich because he’s more productive than I am, and ultimately ends up with more stuff). So to protect my tablemaking, the government decides that each table sale by Bob will carry a five table duty. Now for Bob to trade me the 8 tables I asked for, he’d have to give up 48. It’s no longer in his best interest to trade with me, so the trade doesn’t take place. But we’re both poorer for it.
The same happens internally, and not just because of tariffs. It could be the government overhead in paperwork - if every trade I make with Bob costs me a half-day of form-filling, I may choose not to trade with him. Or it could be taxation. If the tax on the profit of the transaction is too high, we may choose not to trade. Or it could be other inefficiencies - I make a five chair profit from the trade, but shipping it costs six chairs. So I won’t trade. Build better roads, lower the shipping costs to 4 chairs, and suddenly the trades take place and wealth increases.
That’s how economies grow.