We’ll be discussing and debating ideas from the Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith. Whoo!
Sort of an experimental idea for a thread. It’s too big a topic to take on in one OP, so I hope for it to be more of a continuing discussion, as some GD threads are. We’ll see how it works.
This is inspired by the relatively recent thread on the Labor Theory of Value. As I said there, “[A]nyone who settles exclusively with Das Kapital without also engaging with Smith is doing themselves a major disservice”. So… yeah. Why not do that?
Unfortunately, his 18th century prose style is not to everyone’s taste. But that’s what the thread is for. People can engage the ideas here if they can’t engage with the original, or even if they have no interest in picking up the original. The ideas are the thing.
Background for the Importance of the Book
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations is still one of the finest books on economics ever written.
That is extremely weird. Bizarre. It shouldn’t make sense given what we’ve learned in the subsequent 240 years and the relative competition that the book should’ve had. But still, I think it’s true. What happened after its publication is that the early successors to Adam Smith ceded (most of the) ground which he had dominated. They (mostly) didn’t bother to compete on the same level, in the same way, because that would have been pointless. Anyone interested in the topic would have already read it. It didn’t need a competitor, but rather some clean up around the edges.
But about a hundred years after the book, something changed: the marginal revolution in economics. The details aren’t important right now, but Walras and the others created a new approach to market issues, and the legacy of the change was that economics in general became more mathematical and less talky-talky. Adam Smith is engaged in a grand discussion of history, culture, politics, and economics. But economics after the revolution became more formal and math-based, and so necessarily less historically focused. Mastering the technical formalism became the new goal, and that left much less time available for digressions into the medieval class conflict between the feudal aristocrats and the burghers living in the cities – the kinds of topics that captured the attention of both Adam Smith and of course later Marx.
A modern textbook is still talky-talky in a way, in that it is filled with long wordy descriptions of economics. But these long descriptions still sit firmly in the new technical tradition. The words are not being spent so much on history or society or politics, but predominantly on an attempt to describe equations, either explicitly or implicitly.
The equations themselves, while obviously very useful in the right contexts, are NOT an attempt to describe market interactions exactly as they work in reality. The equations are an attempt to create an abstraction of market interactions where cause and effect are more easily seen and understood. They mostly do a great job of this. Mostly.
The price of the abstraction is taking a firm step away from an examination of real market interactions. We draw supply and demand on the blackboard. The curves represent equations. The equations cross at a single point, for which we can solve graphically (“The lines cross here!”) or algebraically. But the equations only “exist” in formalized contexts. A pure supply curve, for instance, is not actually supposed to apply to the vast majority of markets in which we interact every day. Technically speaking, it pops out of pure competition where all firms are so small they have to accept the market price, and that’s an indisputable minority of real-world markets. Supply curves? For the most part, they don’t really “exist” if we want to apply the formalism formally.
Most of the time, we draw the two curves on the board anyway. Eh. It’s useful.
The shift to that formalism in modern economics leaves much less time for the historical digressions, the philosophical musings, the earnest conversation with other thinkers of the day into how the world actually works. The Wealth of Nations has all this nice juicy stuff.
It’s fucking great.
Surprisingly little in the book is original to it (and not everything attributed to the book by later critics is accurate) but the work represents the best and most complete attempt by a classical economist of creating a comprehensive system to describe the workings of a market economy. And what’s astonishing is that despite the occasional error, and even despite lacking a fully modern theory of value, a great deal of economics to this day can be seen as an elaboration on Adam Smith, as an abstract generalization of the system that he originally put together, rather than a complete overturning of that system. A goodly chunk of what you should get in a decent intro class, you also get from Smith, but with the Wealth of Nations you get it with a thousand times more deliberation, compassion, historical context, and wry observation than you should reasonably expect from the average textbook or teacher.
So yeah. Still one of the best.
And thankfully, the book lacks the self-righteous moralizing and analytical superficiality that characterizes so much of popular economics discussion today. That does not mean he is uncritical of the self-interested monopolizing of certain classes of people.
But such criticism is moderated by an appreciation that people act according to the incentives that they’re given. Chunks of the book are broadsides against the rapacious East India Company’s murderous treatment of the Bengal natives. (The great early economists were all strongly against the horrors of colonialism even as their writings were sometimes later perverted to support it).
But even in his strongest condemnation, the criticism is moderated by an appreciation of the circumstances. Adam Smith was not one to fall for the Fundamental Attribution Error.
It’s the last sentence that cuts.
In short, what we see from Adam Smith is an appreciation for human nature, for how people tend to behave in the circumstances they often find themselves in. It is an appreciation for how people actually are in that particular context, rather than any idealized version. Terry Pratchett actually has one of my favorite short quotes on this:
And not for an economist either.
This split between taking people as they are, rather than planning to re-engineer them into what we’d like them to be, I think represents one of the core differences between Adam Smith and someone like Karl Marx.
What else do we get from the book?
What are the other advantages from going old rather than exploring the new?
The first and most important thing we gain is a window into discussions about problems that still face us today. Even economics has a few timeless truths, and many of those truths are embedded in the Wealth of Nations.
We also get a deeper appreciation for the difficulty of these problems. Not just the difficulty of dealing with them as a society, but the plain old difficulty in understanding the underlying nature of the problem in the first place. There was not a single physicist in the 18th century who would be more qualified than a physicist today. But Adam Smith? He was a better economist than I am now. He was a better economist than any economist I personally know. That is a surprising, humbling, and even embarrassing realization. Obviously we know more now than he did then. I’m a better monetary economist than he was. But I simply don’t have the same general intellectual temperament of calm deliberation that allows an application of our extra centuries of knowledge into careful conclusions that put together all the puzzle pieces into a complete picture that doesn’t leave anything important out. If you sent me back to Smith’s time, I could write an economics tome that would stand for all the ages. It would be revolutionary in every way, and my name would go down in history.
And even with twenty years of work, I still doubt it would be even half as good as what Adam Smith accomplished. It’s just damn embarrassing to realize that.
Adam Smith dealt with many of the same problems we clearly recognize today, but in a smaller context, in a slower moving way. There were fewer industries, and those industries could be more closely scrutinized under a watchful eye. That is to say that it was easier to see the whole picture at once at the very beginning of the Industrial Revolution. The picture wasn’t as big, and it wasn’t (yet) shifting so quickly under direct observation. When we look at these old debates and problems in their more manageable historical scale, it’s easier to get into our heads the underlying principles of how the puzzle pieces fit together to form a picture. And once we have those underlying principles, we can generalize from them and hope to gain some measure of insight into issues today.
There is yet another advantage of going old instead of new. By looking at how our predecessors struggled with the same sorts of problems that we struggle with, we can gain a surprising new perspective even on ideas that we previously thought we fully understood. My recent re-reading of the book cast some light onto modern economic models that I would never have considered otherwise. It’s helpful to compare how Adam Smith would approach a problem, to the way I’ve been trained to approach the same sort of problem. Looking at the historical development of ideas over time can give us an entirely fresh perspective on what we might have thought was old boring stuff.
So let’s do it.